ePublic Goods. Is the internet making new public goods?
Keywords: Public Goods, Internet, Media, Copyright, Market Failure, File Sharing, ePublic Goods
An Explanation of the Mass Failure in the Market: the Internet – the Creator of ePublic Goods
An Explanation of the Mass Failure in the Market: the Internet – the Creator of ePublic Goods
First
published: October 9, 2010
Abstract
Media and entertainment industries are declining; profitability is down due to ‘freer computer access. Is the internet producing ‘Public goods’ from what were Private goods? With respect to these goods and the Internet, the assumption used to classify ‘Private goods' and Public goods in an economy (the degree of excludability and rivalry) was analysed, and the respective industries were tested for being Public Goods. It was concluded that these goods within the entertainment/media industries are slowly being repositioned from what is termed 'private' or 'club'/'congestion' goods to their extreme opposite, public goods. The ‘free rider problem’ of Public Goods has become the ‘free copy problem’ with respect to these goods. It was hypothesised the Internet was the cause. It was discussed Public Goods – by tradition – fail in the market and are therefore provided by the Government: is this to be the destiny of Internet goods or any item on the Internet subject to file-sharing or digital copying in any form, including – at the extreme – the human genome, solid object 3D printing, and even money in the form of bitcoins?
Media and entertainment industries are declining; profitability is down due to ‘freer computer access. Is the internet producing ‘Public goods’ from what were Private goods? With respect to these goods and the Internet, the assumption used to classify ‘Private goods' and Public goods in an economy (the degree of excludability and rivalry) was analysed, and the respective industries were tested for being Public Goods. It was concluded that these goods within the entertainment/media industries are slowly being repositioned from what is termed 'private' or 'club'/'congestion' goods to their extreme opposite, public goods. The ‘free rider problem’ of Public Goods has become the ‘free copy problem’ with respect to these goods. It was hypothesised the Internet was the cause. It was discussed Public Goods – by tradition – fail in the market and are therefore provided by the Government: is this to be the destiny of Internet goods or any item on the Internet subject to file-sharing or digital copying in any form, including – at the extreme – the human genome, solid object 3D printing, and even money in the form of bitcoins?
1 Introduction
While there has been much (probably unfounded) concern over the effect of new computer technology on labour markets, the real problem with computers may lie with the internet and its impact on markets. Can the current demise of the entertainment and media industries be explained by the internet creating ‘Public Goods? ePublic Goods. Newspapers, TV, movie and music production and the like have slowly diminished since the advent of the Internet and have been scrambling for new models that pay. All of these firms are ‘hit’ by the proliferation of their copyrighted material on the Internet.Notwithstanding attempts to extend their respective industries, to a great extent, there is market failure. This paper claims this failure is due to the Internet producing an
environment of ‘Public Goods. For this to be so, there must be evidence of
a ‘free rider’ problem, non-excludability and non-rivalry – in the respective
industries – all due to the Internet. If true, it may seem trivial on the outside,
however on the inside, a problem rises; traditionally, public goods tend to almost
always be supported by Government. What does this mean for investigative
journalism? Will it lead to support from the government under a merit-good rationale?
“Public goods are goods that are both non-excludable and non-rival. Consumers cannot be prevented from consuming them once they are provided and additional consumers do not reduce the amount left for other people, e.g. national defence. Once a country is defended all of its inhabitants benefit automatically. Many public goods such as lighthouses could in theory be provided by the market mechanism but are not; these are called 'quasi-public goods', rather than 'pure public goods'. Public goods suffer from the free-rider problem. If asked whether they would pay for them, households would lie and say no because, once provided, they could benefit for free anyway. Because no one is willing to pay for these goods (because they hope someone else will) they will not be provided in a free
1.1 Public Goods
While teaching market failure in my economics class recently and analysing examples of ‘public’ and ‘private’ goods, I noticed newspapers and the like—at least in their digital form—are akin to radio, where radio can be consumed in either pay-per-listen or free-to-air form. Newspapers have similar problems to those of Public goods. So, what is a public good? The following is taken from a regular economics textbook.“Public goods are goods that are both non-excludable and non-rival. Consumers cannot be prevented from consuming them once they are provided and additional consumers do not reduce the amount left for other people, e.g. national defence. Once a country is defended all of its inhabitants benefit automatically. Many public goods such as lighthouses could in theory be provided by the market mechanism but are not; these are called 'quasi-public goods', rather than 'pure public goods'. Public goods suffer from the free-rider problem. If asked whether they would pay for them, households would lie and say no because, once provided, they could benefit for free anyway. Because no one is willing to pay for these goods (because they hope someone else will) they will not be provided in a free
market. Therefore, the Government must provide them. (Note: for a 'private good' if
one unit is consumed by one person it cannot be consumed by another. (This is not
the case for public goods.)” [1]
Non-rivalry may be broken down to whether the consumers' experience of the good or service is diminished by the use of another consumer; are the consumers ‘bothered’ by the practice of someone – or themselves – getting something for (next to) no cost? The answer, without any research, is – no. Unlike the use of other traditional ‘Private’ or ‘Common goods’ (figure 1 below) – print newspapers, recorded music – there is no rivalry or bother by others the 'stealing' or copying of the good. The community do not show concern or fight for the media as they would for the exploitation of ‘Common goods’ – the whales in the oceans or pollution in the atmosphere. As a consequence of this non-excludability and non-rivalry, the entertainment and media industries or anything subject to file-sharing or digital copying in any form, have slowly been re-positioned from being private or club/congestion goods to an opposite domain, public goods – as shown in the table below.
1.2 Public Goods and the Internet - ePublic Goods
The Internet must show evidence of non-excludability and non-rivalry to create an environment for public goods. Non-excludability may be evident in how the said goods and services are now sold: consumers can view – most, if not all – the product (news articles) online without paying. This is unlike the classic examples of a lighthouse or streetlight, but the effect is similar; the firm has lost control of access: if the consumer cannot get from one provider of news, they will (easily) find a substitute, and if an access fee is applied online, this will also lead consumers to likely search for a free substitute. Firms are forced into competitive ‘gameplay’ to offer material for free. For the music and movie industry, much is available on YouTube, and if not YouTube, a close substitute to it – copies can easily be made by consumers. Entertainment goods are proliferated throughout the Internet, and this is extremely difficult to police; if a copy is found by a firm to be ‘pirated’, this copy may be ‘taken down’ – only to see copies soon available somewhere else, sometime in the future.Non-rivalry may be broken down to whether the consumers' experience of the good or service is diminished by the use of another consumer; are the consumers ‘bothered’ by the practice of someone – or themselves – getting something for (next to) no cost? The answer, without any research, is – no. Unlike the use of other traditional ‘Private’ or ‘Common goods’ (figure 1 below) – print newspapers, recorded music – there is no rivalry or bother by others the 'stealing' or copying of the good. The community do not show concern or fight for the media as they would for the exploitation of ‘Common goods’ – the whales in the oceans or pollution in the atmosphere. As a consequence of this non-excludability and non-rivalry, the entertainment and media industries or anything subject to file-sharing or digital copying in any form, have slowly been re-positioned from being private or club/congestion goods to an opposite domain, public goods – as shown in the table below.
1.2.1 The Free Rider (free copy) Problem and the Internet
The ‘smoking gun’ evidence of this ‘internet creating public goods’ claim is the presence of the free-rider problem. Consumers are not getting a free ride but rather are – in this case, quite literally – getting a free copy. When asked to pay by a market provider, consumers simply find a substitute or find a free copy elsewhere (on the internet). And for music and films, copies are made 'free' by file sharing and the like.2 Discussions and Conclusions
Firms in the arts and entertainment industry demand revenue if they are to survive. While there has been an adaptive response to this problem of market decline: Spotify and the like for music provision, Netflix and the like for movies, and bands are concert touring more, it does not seem to totally satisfy the concern of those in the industries to survive, to profit. There is clearly a major decline.The problem is that public goods tend to fail as a business operation and are almost always supported by the government; this is of great concern with respect to the future of news media and investigative journalism. Democracy demands or depends upon a 'free from Government' media – can blogging and other social
media meet this problem. We will likely see a ‘mass extinction in print and
arts; this is not to say (at all) this is the end of the market, but it is a massive
change.
The problem of mass-market failure may be extended if we include other flows of knowledge and information regarding modern tech: the genome, knowledge in general, anything that can be digitally printed, including solid-object 3D printing, and even money in the form of bitcoins.
There is a great paradox here that one of humanity's great accomplishments, the Internet, may be our own slow undoing. It is as if the Internet has formed some kind of economic black hole. Is there any escaping? Our own privacy on the Internet may well fall under this public goods paradox also, including—in the future—one's genome.
References
1. Gillespie A. Advanced Economics Through Diagrams. Oxford University Press; 2001.
The problem of mass-market failure may be extended if we include other flows of knowledge and information regarding modern tech: the genome, knowledge in general, anything that can be digitally printed, including solid-object 3D printing, and even money in the form of bitcoins.
There is a great paradox here that one of humanity's great accomplishments, the Internet, may be our own slow undoing. It is as if the Internet has formed some kind of economic black hole. Is there any escaping? Our own privacy on the Internet may well fall under this public goods paradox also, including—in the future—one's genome.
References
1. Gillespie A. Advanced Economics Through Diagrams. Oxford University Press; 2001.
Using our present economic paradigm, it would appear, on the face of it at least, that you are correct: digital media will become public goods.
ReplyDeleteIs this necessarily a bad thing?
A different paradigm from which to assess this may prove useful, and it does seem a (large, very) paradigm change is imminent, does it not?
The prospect of having one's product become a public good alters the producer's motivations, and once again, this may prove a very good thing from a different paradigm.
I look forward to reading your other, and future posts soon. This is the most interesting new blog I have found in a very long while. I too have been thinking much about fractals and economics, but have not yet posted upon this directly. I will soon. I can see you have many ideas that I would like to contemplate.
My thoughts involving fractals are mainly intuitive, which presents challenges when verbalizing.
I'd be interested to know what you would make of Freegold in relation to public goods, and fractals.
"The problem is that public goods tend to fail as a business operation, and are almost always supported - whether by hand or money - by the Government." - This has been a problem of most businesses. You just can't rely too much on public goods.
ReplyDeletebusiness consultant